Home
| Databases
| WorldLII
| Search
| Feedback
University of Melbourne Law School Research Series |
Last Updated: 6 April 2011
The Regulatory Impact of Using Public Procurement to
Promote Better Labour Standards in Corporate Supply Chains
John Howe[∗]
This paper was first published in K. Macdonald and S. Marshall (eds) Fair Trade, Corporate Accountability and Beyond: Experiments in Globalising Justice (Ashgate, 2010)
Introduction
This chapter examines the potential of government
procurement as a mechanism for improving job quality and alleviating poverty and
proposes ways in which these mechanisms can be strengthened so as to make them
more effective. The promotion of higher labour standards
through government
procurement is a ‘soft’ law mechanism that may appeal to governments
at a time when economic globalization
has, among other things, reduced the
political willingness and ability of governments to safeguard the welfare of
workers and communities
through the maintenance of conventional labour law
systems. In many developed economies, governments have reduced their traditional
legal protection of labour rights and standards. Many developing countries
maintain strong labour laws ‘on paper’ but
lack resources, adequate
institutional frameworks and, at times, the will to properly enforce labour
standards. This chapter assumes,
however, that governments have a crucial role
to play in promoting and enforcing labour standards. The difficulties of
enforcement
and the high disincentives to compliance with labour laws for
businesses mean that governments must find innovative ways to create
inducements
for more widespread compliance with labour standards. It is the contention of
this chapter that promotion of existing
labour standards or higher than existing
legal standards through government procurement may be effective because it is
responsive
to existing power and resource distribution among economic and social
actors (Ayres and Braithwaite, 1992; Teubner, 1983).
Poor job quality and
labour abuses continue to be major causes of poverty and human degradation
around the world. This is especially
prevalent in developing countries. This is
especially prevalent in developing countries. It is widely accepted that
improvements
in internal labour standards can assist the reduction of poverty in
developing countries significantly (see, for example, DFID 2004).
One response
to the ‘ossification’ of labour law and enforcement (Estlund 2002)
has been the proliferation of private
or non-governmental labour regulation and
governance. This has been exemplified by the actions of NGOs and trade unions to
persuade
and/or pressure multinational corporations to sign on to codes of
conduct or other voluntary standards as forms of supply chain regulation,
often
within the rubric of ‘corporate social responsibility’ (CSR). As
well as functioning to enhance domestic observance
of better labour practices,
these non-governmental approaches are commonly used to supplement international
labour regulation of
the operations of transnational corporations in developing
countries.
Questions have been raised about the desirability and
effectiveness of non-governmental regulation and CSR as a strategy for improving
labour standards in the absence of state regulation (see for instance: Heeks and
Duncombe 2003, 1; Utting in this collection). The
challenge facing state and
non-state actors willing to locate and hold businesses accountable to labour
standards – whether
these are enshrined in law, are above the floor of
minimum standards, or are more aspirational goals – is the actual or
perceived
conflict between these standards and the main drivers of corporate
business activity: profit-seeking and shareholder value (Parker
2007). This
conflict is not easily overcome.
One mechanism by which governments can
leverage corporate responsibility for labour standards without using mandatory
legal regulation
is through public procurement: making government purchases of
goods and services conditional upon contractors and supply chains observing
desired labour practices linked to job quality criteria. The significant role of
governments as purchasers of goods and services
provides the necessary economic
leverage against corporate resistance, while being more politically palatable by
avoiding the use
of law to mandate broadly applicable standards. Procurement can
be used to promote better labour standards domestically as well as
allowing
governments of developed countries to influence the observance of labour
standards by businesses operating in developing
countries.
Government
procurement is an interesting site for analysis of labour regulation, as
expansion in government purchasing is itself a
symptom of the transformation of
the state from ‘public provider’ of goods and services and direct
regulator of corporate
activity to a phase of ‘regulatory
capitalism’ (Braithwaite 2005), where the state plays more of a role in
enabling or
facilitating economic activity and self-regulation. Examining
government procurement as a technique of labour regulation is also
an
opportunity to reflect on the maintenance and extension of the notion of
government as ‘model employer’ (McCrudden
2007).
The
potential impact of government procurement as a mechanism for improving
job quality and alleviating poverty is the focus of this chapter. While
government procurement initiatives which seek to promote better labour practices
in a domestic context will be considered, greater
emphasis is placed on the
possible use of procurement to promote better labour standards in developing
countries. This chapter will
examine various instances in which developed
countries are linking procurement with supply chain governance mechanisms in
order to
reach suppliers in developing countries with lower living standards.
One issue considered is the tension between social objectives
and economic
efficiency values inherent in any attempt to use government purchasing to
address social concerns. This may bring procurement
mechanisms into tension
multilateral and bilateral ‘free trade’ agreements. Further, this
chapter investigates the extent
to which this mechanism of regulation is likely
to be a legitimate and effective means of bringing about greater organisational
commitment
to better labour standards. In doing so, the chapter also analyses
the actual and potential interaction between procurement and other
strands of
regulation and governance, including traditional state labour regulation and
non-governmental approaches.
Government Procurement as Regulatory Technique
Government
procurement can be characterised as a specific regulatory technique or approach
available to the state. It can be distinguished
from direct legal and private
regulation or voluntary CSR. This chapter adopts a broad understanding of
regulation
as any process or set of processes by which norms are established, the
behaviour of those subject to the norms monitored or fed back
into the regime,
and for which there are mechanisms for holding the behaviour of regulated actors
within the acceptable limits of
the regime (whether by enforcement action or by
some other mechanism) (Scott 2001, 331).
The focus of this chapter is on the
role of the nation state in regulating labour standards. Regulation may, of
course, occur ‘above
and beyond the state’ (Morgan and Yeung 2007).
The promulgation of labour standards by the International Labour Organisation
(ILO) is an example of such international regulation. Some consideration will be
given to the interaction between state regulation
and regulation by the ILO
later in this chapter.
In seeking to influence behaviour through the
establishment, monitoring and enforcement of norms, the state has a number of
regulatory
techniques and approaches available to it. Of these alternative
techniques, ‘soft’ or ‘light touch’ approaches
to
regulation are distinguished from ‘hard’ legal or centred
‘command and control’ regulation – in
which formal rules are
created, monitored and enforced by the state through orders and sanctions
– on the basis that the former
are less reliant on government imposition
of generally applicable mandatory legal standards as a means of regulating
behaviour (Ogus
2001; Howe and Landau 2007). Moreover, it is recognised that
regulation is ‘multifaceted, differentiated and increasingly
“shared”
by a range of public and private actors’ (Lucio and
Mackenzie 2004, 78).
Approaches vary and are rarely mutually exclusive across
this spectrum of labour regulation. Many initiatives rely on government
deployment
of its wealth resource to secure behavioural change in order to avoid
the use of ‘hard’ law. Such initiatives include
attaching conditions
to procurement contracts and offering of financial incentives or rewards in
return for desired behaviour (Howe
2006). Some approaches employ
‘meta-regulation’ – in other words, facilitation of
‘co-regulation’ or
corporatist arrangements and/or
‘self-regulation’ by requiring or encouraging firms and stakeholders
to develop standards
of behaviour which are better than state sanctioned minima
(Parker 2007). Another broad area of government action is use of information
and
education strategies designed to encourage the adoption of decent work practices
by presenting socially responsible or ethical
practices in a way which suggests
consistency with ideals of good corporate (self-)governance (Weiss, 2002).
Information strategies
include those which impose public disclosure requirements
on firms, including ‘triple bottom line’ reporting, as well
as
dissemination of voluntary codes of practice, and ‘best practice
guidelines’ or ‘case studies’.
There is a growing interest
in alternatives to command and control regulation, including public procurement,
such as government ‘drivers’
of CSR (Moon, 2004; Barnard, Deakin and
Hobbs, 2004). This extends to consideration of the role that some of these
regulatory approaches
might take in influencing the labour practices of
multinational corporations beyond the borders of the host state (Cooney, 2004).
CSR tends to encapsulate voluntary initiatives, or at least initiatives adopted
by companies as a result of pressure from social
movements rather than as a
result of government regulation. The basic assumption of CSR campaigns is that
enterprises will respect
labour standards if this respect is shown to be a
relevant factor in maintaining or enhancing competitiveness and higher
productivity.
However, while ‘command and control’ regulation
frequently fails to ensure that corporations comply with important social
policy
goals, it is also true that many corporations, when left to their own devices,
fail to take CSR seriously (for example Cooney
2006; Jones, Marshall and
Mitchell 2007; McBarnet 2007, 14). This failure is exacerbated when it comes to
corporate responsibility
to employees, where studies have suggested that
employers will often conceive of CSR as ‘incorporating a set of external
issues
concerning the image and reputation of the company rather than the issue
of its employment conditions’ (Barnard, Deakin and
Hobbs 2004, 30). The
difference between voluntary CSR and light touch regulation, such as the use of
targeted monetary incentives,
is the role the state plays in seeking to steer or
leverage corporate governance to internalise public policy goals. An example of
this is the goal to procure better labour standards through the different tools
at its disposal.
Soft or light touch approaches to state regulation have
become increasingly popular with governments in the era of regulatory
capitalism.
It is arguable that this is because, in the context of economic
globalization and increased competition among nation states for private
investment, governments are either fearful of, or ideologically opposed to, the
use of command and control regulation, for fear of
causing corporate flight.
Light touch regulation is seen as more consistent with the ‘business
case’ for social responsibility.
Moreover, soft forms of regulation are
not always subject to the same jurisdictional and/or constitutional limitations
as more formal
law. However, they do represent a continuing role for government
in the establishment of norms and mechanisms for securing compliance
with those
norms. The key issue here is whether these alternative forms of regulation are
effective. Do they induce the desired responses from firms?
Evaluating Procurement as Regulation
There are a number of
different criteria by which different regulatory techniques and systems can be
evaluated. In this chapter, the
potential impact of procurement as a technique
for promoting better labour standards will be assessed in terms of the
overlapping
concepts of effectiveness and legitimacy.
We can anticipate that
asking contractors to ensure that their transnational supply chains comply with
specified labour standards
might meet some resistance. While the incorporation
of labour standards into government procurement programs will have at least some
symbolic significance, empirical studies of regulation have consistently
established that it cannot be assumed that state promulgated
standards will be
effective, even where they are backed by penalties and other sanctions for
non-compliance. It is therefore worthwhile
thinking about ways in which
procurement might be designed in order to maximise effectiveness.
Regulatory
scholars and scholars influenced by discourse incorporating systems theory argue
that regulation is more likely to be effective
if used in a manner which is
reflexive or responsive to existing power and resource distribution among
economic and social actors
(Ayres and Braithwaite, 1992; Teubner, 1983). These
discourses reflect some common themes. One of the most significant of these is
the contention that state regulation is simply one of a number of interacting
and competing regulatory systems (Cooney 2006). Many
scholars have argued that
states should be seeking to harness or enlist these non-state systems in order
to achieve public policy
objectives, rather than seeking to interfere with or
override those systems, because the latter approach is frequently ineffective
in
changing non-state behaviour. In other words, government should ‘work with
the grain of things’, seeking to shape
and steer forms of private ordering
or self-regulation, such as corporate governance. It should not demand change
through mandatory
legal regulation or ‘command and control’, which
is prone to avoidance (Braithwaite 2005; Cooney 2004; Arup 2001).
In doing
so, regulation should be designed to facilitate or encourage
‘de-centred’ models of regulation, whereby non-state
actors are
responsible, empowered participants in norm creation, implementation and
monitoring and enforcement (Black 2001). Indeed,
it has been argued that an
important criteria of effectiveness in any regulatory regime is its legitimacy,
in the sense that it is
‘worthy of public support’ (Baldwin and Cave
1999). While this can be assessed in a number of ways, I will argue in this
chapter that the legitimacy and therefore the effectiveness of any government
policy will be influenced by the quality of public
deliberation and
participation by various stakeholders when determining regulatory objectives and
the mechanisms for achieving those
objectives (Vincent-Jones, 2006).
Some
models which draw on these ideas are based on ‘enforced
self-regulation’ or ‘co-regulation’, where ‘instead
of
insisting on corporate compliance with state-mandated rules, governments can
instead require corporations to institute internal
systems designed to promote
socially desirable outcomes’, often with mandatory involvement of
stakeholders (Cooney 2006, 194-195).
It is important to note that theories
of responsive or reflexive regulation do not necessarily leave development of
these internal
systems entirely in the hands of non-state actors. Barnard,
Deakin and Hobbs have argued that ‘[a] crucial aspect of reflexive
law is
that it involves not simply an attempt to delegate rule-making authority to
self-regulatory mechanisms such as collective
bargaining, but also an effort to
use legal norms, procedures and sanctions to ‘frame’ or
‘steer’ the process
of self-regulation’ (Barnard, Deakin and
Hobbs 2004, 4).
This would not necessarily require legislation. It has also
been suggested that states can facilitate development of internal systems,
involving multiple stakeholders, by deploying their wealth resource as an
incentive to corporations to internalize public policy
norms, or more democratic
decision-making processes (Parker 2002, 29; Cooney 2004).
What else is
likely to be effective in convincing an organization to embrace public policy
goals and values such as improvement of
labour standards? Johnstone and Jones
suggest that the answer to the more general question of regulatory effectiveness
lies in regulation
which is constitutive at the level of the firm (Johnstone and
Jones 2006). Their study of OHS, dismissal, discrimination and sexual
harassment regulation suggests that constitutive regulation exists where
‘demands are placed on employers to discover and understand
regulatory
requirements, engage appropriate personnel (including advisers), establish and
implement appropriate policies and procedures,
and monitor and evaluate the
implementation of those procedures to ensure that the organization complies with
these regulatory requirements’
(Johnstone and Jones 2006, 501).
Finally, it must be born in mind that pluralism in regulation will not
necessarily be productive and effective. The overlaying of
procurement or other
alternative regulatory approaches over existing mechanisms of labour regulation
may lead to ‘regulatory
collision’ which undermines the objective of
using procurement in this way (Johnstone and Mitchell 2004). Design of
regulation
must take account of the potential for unproductive regulatory
conflict if it is to be legitimate and effective.
Procurement as a Form of Labour Regulation
Government procurement
is an extremely significant area of government economic activity. The OECD
estimates that globally, public
procurement expenditure accounts for 15 percent
of the world’s Gross Domestic Product (OECD 2005, 35). In Australia alone,
it has been estimated that the Commonwealth Government annual procurement budget
is in excess of $16 billion dollars, a figure which
does not take into account
State and Local Government procurement expenditure (Cooney 2004, 340). In larger
economies, the government
procurement budget is of course even more significant.
For example, while annual central government expenditure in the UK amounts
to
£15 billion, total public sector procurement exceeds £150 billion
(Bell and Usher 2007). The extent of public procurement
is in itself a sign of
the transformation in government. Governments have moved away from direct
provision of many goods and services,
and are instead purchasing those services
from the private sector.
While it might be argued that the immediate purpose
of procurement is the purchase of goods and services necessary for government
administration, and that this is largely an economic purpose which should be
subject to evaluation by economic efficiency criteria,
government procurement,
as a form of social regulation, has a long history. Particularly since the early
20th century, if not earlier, procurement has been used
to regulate labour practices, and governments in many countries continue to do
so, including Australia, Canada, the United States and the UK (McCrudden,
2007).
The ILO has promoted the inclusion of labour considerations within
public procurement contracts since the late 1940s. The Labor Clauses (Public
Contracts) Convention 1949 (No. 94) provides that all public procurement
contracts awarded by central public authorities must include clauses ensuring
wages,
hours of work and other conditions of labour which are no less favourable
than those established for work of the same character in
the trade or industry
concerned, in the district where the work is carried out (ILO 1949; ILO
2008).
This latter requirement begs the question of the reach of
labour regulation through procurement. Given that this chapter is concerned with
the use of procurement as a tool for achieving
better labour standards and
alleviating poverty, it will distinguish between procurement used to achieve
better labour conditions
in the ‘home’ country, and procurement
seeking to influence labour standards in other countries where labour and living
standards are poorer than in the home country. For this reason, the chapter will
focus on developments in Australia, the United States
and the United Kingdom.
This chapter presents evidence that public procurement is not extensively
used as a form of labour regulation (see also ILO 2008).
Before examining the
way in which procurement is used to regulate labour practices, it is first
necessary to consider some of the
different forms and geographies of
procurement, as well as how it might be used to achieve social objectives.
Government procurement
can be categorised according to whether it is public
works, goods or services that are purchased (McCrudden 2007). This
categorisation
will be relevant to whether procurement can be used to influence
labour standards, and the extent of regulation possible. For example,
procurement of public works such as construction will normally be limited to
domestic companies and workers. In this context, linking
labour criteria to
procurement will only impact on the conditions of domestic workers. Procurement
linkages with labour standards
concerning the purchase of public works and
services are relatively common. However, where governments purchase goods such
as equipment,
clothing, stationary and so on, suppliers of those goods may have
sourced products or components from overseas. It is within this
context that
governments of developed economies can influence labour conditions in developing
countries most strongly. Yet, as will
be shown, this is also a difficult
proposition for governments, and examples of linkages between goods procurement
and labour standards
are relatively rare.
There are two ways in which
governments can procure goods so that they promote better labour standards.
Firstly, governments can simply
procure goods which are certified as ‘fair
trade’ or ‘ethically produced’ by a recognised certification
agency.
Fair trade certification would normally require compliance with at least
the core labour standards (Bell and Usher 2007, 9). Of course,
there is only a
limited range of goods attracting fair trade or some other recognised
certification and governments are also significant
purchasers of services.
Secondly, governments can require contractors supplying goods to comply with
specified labour standards,
in the same way that they might regulate the supply
of services.
Assuming that a government takes the latter approach to
achieving social objectives through goods and services procurement, there
are
three stages at which governments can impose labour standards: qualification or
eligibility to tender for a government contract;
the tender assessment process;
and the contractual requirements imposed on the successful tenderer (McCrudden
2007).
By imposing standards as ‘qualification’ criteria,
Government can restrict the tendering process to those companies that already
comply with social objectives such as labour
standards, thus providing an
incentive for companies wishing to obtain government contracts to observe the
desired minimum standards.
There are various ways in which governments can
integrate labour standard considerations into the tender assessment process. A
programme
could identify a quota of contracts which are ‘set
aside’ for contractors of a particular type. There may be a
‘price preference’ for certain types of contractor, where,
for example, the bid submitted by bidder A, although higher than that of
tenderer B, is regarded
as equal to that of B if A undertakes to implement a
particular social policy. The past practice or the willingness of a past bidder
to implement the social objectives may be taken into account as a
‘tie-breaker’ where otherwise equal tenderers are in
competition.
Alternatively, the social criteria may be either just one consideration to take
into account, or determinative where
tenders are otherwise equal. Another
approach may be to ‘offer back’ to preferred tenderers,
allowing them to match the lowest bid of the non-preferred tenderer.
However,
the approach of many Australian governments, for example, is to include labour
standards as one of a number of different
criteria, including value for money,
upon which tenders will be assessed, without clear weighting given to each
element of the criteria
(Howe and Landau 2007). Such an approach leaves
considerable space for labour-related considerations to be subsumed within, or
overlooked
by, government administrators under pressure to secure best value for
money, which is assessed narrowly in terms of the cheapest
available
price.
Alternatively, governments and their procuring agencies can require
successful tenderers to demonstrate ongoing compliance with labour
standards as
a performance condition of the contract. Contracts might provide a mechanism for
monitoring of compliance, such as contractor
reporting, and termination of the
contract can be used a penalty for non-compliance, thus aiding enforcement of
any labour-related
conditions.
Of course, the effectiveness of all of these
approaches will depend on the veracity of information provided to procuring
authorities
and on the adequacy and effectiveness of monitoring mechanisms. This
issue will be discussed later in the chapter, as it is a consideration
which
also arises in relation to non-governmental mechanisms for promoting better
labour standards.
Another consideration here is the role of law in relation
to public procurement and labour standards. ILO Convention 94 assumes
that ratifying states would enact legislation to regulate the social aspects of
public procurement. However, in the jurisdictions
I have examined for the
purpose of this chapter, including Australia, the US and the UK, it is apparent
that where social criteria
are incorporated into public procurement, this is
achieved through administrative action and contract rather than through
legislation.
Assuming that labour standards are included in public
procurement tender assessment and contractual performance criteria, there are
two broad types of labour standard which may be linked to public procurement
programmes (Howe 2006). Firstly, procurement may be
used as a method of
enforcing existing legal obligations either domestically or in a
supplier’s host country; that is, as a supplement to existing mechanisms
for
enforcement of minimum rights and standards set by legislation and/or
applicable industrial instruments, including ILO conventions
or the ILO’s
Core Labour Standards (CLS). Secondly, procurement may be used to advance
desired modes of labour relations above and beyond those required by
applicable laws. Thus, for example, while a country may not have a legally
enforceable right to collective bargaining,
recognition of trade unions and the
practice of collective bargaining may be encouraged through procurement.
Incidence of Public Procurement as a Form of Transnational Labour
Regulation
In Australia, public procurement by the Commonwealth and the
various State governments and their agencies is governed by a complex
web of
policies, frameworks, codes and guidelines (see generally Howe and Landau 2007,
373-380). In each jurisdiction, there is a
broad procurement policy or framework
that sets out general principles applying to government procurement contracts.
Both Commonwealth
and State governments include at least some labour conditions
in their procurement criteria. In the case of Victoria, one of the
broad
policies requires all businesses that tender for government contracts to adhere
to an ‘ethical employment standard’
(Victorian Government Purchasing
Board 2003). Queensland and Victoria also have codes of best practice that set
out specific labour
standards and industrial relations practices with which all
businesses in particular industries that tender for government contracts
must
comply. For example, Queensland has codes of practice for the building and
construction industry, call centres and the clothing
industry (Howe and Landau
2007). In NSW, since 2005, there has been a single code of practice governing
all types of government procurement
which sets out standards of behaviour
expected of government agencies, tenderers, service providers, employer and
industry associations,
and unions (Howe and Landau 2007).
While both
Commonwealth and State governments in Australia use public procurement as a
means of promoting labour standards, their
policies differ according to the type
of contract or firm to which the policy applies, the precise standards promoted,
the sanctions
imposed for breach, and the use of monitoring mechanisms (Howe and
Landau 2007). In the case of State governments, compliance is
limited to onshore
businesses – participation in procurement is not made dependent on
offshore suppliers meeting labour standards.
The recently elected Rudd Labour
Government has committed to an ‘ethical procurement policy’ which
will require major
suppliers to the Commonwealth ‘to ensure compliance
with [ethical] procurement policies by all sub-contractors involved in
the
principal's supply chain to the Commonwealth’ (ALP 2007). The Rudd
Government is yet to provide details of how this policy
will work in practice.
Beyond this commitment, there have been only isolated examples of
procurement policies in Australia which have extended to offshore
labour used in
the production of goods. In the lead-up to the Sydney Olympic Games in 2000, the
Sydney Olympic Games Organising Committee
(SOCOG), the NSW Labor Council and the
Australian Council of Trade Unions (ACTU) agreed to a ‘Code of Labour
Practice for Production
of Goods Licensed’ for the Games (SOCOG 1998; Webb
2001). The Code required all manufacturers or suppliers of licensed products
to
certify that they and their contractors and subcontractors (not limited to
‘onshore’ businesses) met specified minimum
labour standards. These
standards included not only core labour standards such as prohibition of child
labour and respect for freedom
of association and collective bargaining, but
also required payment of ‘fair wages’ (at least complying with legal
or
industry minimum standards, and ‘sufficient to meet basic needs and
provide some discretionary income’), that hours of
work were not
excessive, and that a ‘safe and hygienic working environment ... be
provided’ (SOCOG 1998). The Victorian
Government agreed to similar
guidelines to ensure that official clothing and other merchandise for the 2006
Commonwealth Games in
Melbourne was sourced ethically (ACTU 2006).
Queries
have been raised about how far even these rare examples went in terms of
ensuring that goods sourced for the respective Games
were produced in conditions
which met the agreed minimum standards. After the SOCOG Code was agreed to,
unions raised concerns about
whether all licencees’ overseas manufacturers
(mainly in China and Fiji) had been inspected for compliance. SOCOG initially
refused ACTU permission to send a representative to inspect conditions in
overseas factories, or even to provide information regarding
contractors and
subcontractors of licencees (Webb 2001, 213). While SOCOG eventually withdrew
its objections and provided unions
with a list of known contractors and
subcontractors, unions lacked necessary resources to carry out on-site
monitoring.
More innovative developments have taken place in other developed
countries. The incorporation of social policy goals including labour
standards
within public procurement has long been a matter of debate within the European
Union (McCrudden 2007). Several countries
have legislation which requires or
allows government purchasers to include labour clauses in government contracts.
Belgium, Finland
and Austria have especially strong requirements regarding these
labour clauses (ILO 2008, 37). However, these requirements are largely
concerned
with domestic labour conditions. There is also evidence of some European
countries reducing their commitment to attach
labour criteria in procurement
contracts. For example, a recent ILO study found that France had ceased to apply
the ILO Convention
in relation to procurement (ILO 2008, 19).
In terms of
the use of procurement to regulate labour standards across transnational supply
chains, the most significant developments
have been in relation to legal changes
allowing government purchasing of certified fair trade products in several
European countries,
including Belgium, Italy and the United Kingdom (Fairtrade
2007; European Fairtrade Association 2007).
There is a growing interest in
the incorporation of labour standards into procurement by all levels of
government in the UK (Bell
and Usher 2007; Fairtrade 2007). The Office of
Government Commerce provides guidance to UK purchasing authorities on the
incorporation
of social criteria including the ILO CLS and other
‘employment issues’ into different stages of the procurement process
(Office of Government Commerce 2006). Actual implementation of labour standards
through procurement in the UK still seems to be largely
at the discretion of
individual government departments and agencies. While some UK government
departments and some local governments
have committed to purchasing fair trade
certified products (Fairtrade 2007), there is less evidence of more widespread
inclusion
of labour criteria in the purchase of goods and services.
Use of
procurement to regulate labour standards beyond the borders of the purchasing
country appears to be more common in the US,
where federal legislation requires
labour clauses to be included in federal contracts for services and manufactured
goods (McNamara-O’Hara Service Contract Act 41 U.S.C. 351;
Walsh-Healey Public Contracts Act 41 U.S.C. 35). However, it is at State
and local government level where innovation in relation to transnational labour
regulation has occurred.
Many of these innovations are a result of the activist
network Sweatfree Communities persuading many US State and local governments
to
adopt ‘sweatfree’ procurement policies in relation to garment
purchasing. Sweatfree Communities recommends that States
and cities in the US
require suppliers of apparel, footwear and laundry services to comply with some
basic labour standards. These
include the ILO’s core labour standards, but
also any ‘applicable local laws’ in the country where the
manufacturing
takes place, whether the US or another country (Sweatfree
Communities 2006). Sweatfree Communities argues that, if possible, procurement
contracts should also require compliance with a ‘non-poverty wage’
rather than the legal minimum wage. This is because
legal minimum wages in many
countries do not necessarily provide sufficient income to allow workers and
their families to avoid poverty.
Sweatfree Communities suggests that in
countries other than the US, this would be the wage and benefit level to raise a
family three
out of poverty based on the national standard of living index for
that country.
According to Sweatfree Communities, six States and 38 cities
in the US have adopted some form of sweatfree procurement policy (Sweatfree
Communities 2007). While the content of each State and city’s policy
varies, most require that contractors at least comply
with legal minima. Some
States (including California, Illinois, New Jersey and Pennsylvania) and cities
have adopted the non-poverty
wage standard. The city of Los Angeles’
Sweatfree Procurement Ordinance (Ordinance No 176291, adding Article 17 to the
Los
Angeles Administrative Code, Div. 10, Ch. 1) applies to all contracts for
material, supplies, equipment and laundry services where
the value of the
contract exceeds US$25,000 and the term of the contract is in excess of three
months. Under the Ordinance, contractors
with the city must sign a City
Contractors Code of Conduct, whereby the contractor promises to ensure
compliance with ‘all
human and labor rights and labor obligations that are
imposed by treaty or law on the country in which the equipment, supplies, goods
or materials are made and assembled’. In addition, for contracts involving
the procurement of ‘garments, uniforms, foot
apparel and related
accessories’, contractors must ensure that contractors are paid a
‘procurement living wage’
(Sec. 10.43.3.D, Los Angeles
Administrative Code, Div. 1, Ch. 1). For countries outside the US, the relevant
city agency ‘shall
establish a procurement living wage which is comparable
to the wage for domestic manufacturers as defined above, adjusted to reflect
the
country’s level of economic development by using the World Bank’s
Gross National Income per capita Purchasing Power
Parity index’ (Sec.
10.43.3.D, Los Angeles Administrative Code, Div. 1, Ch. 1). Successful
contractors are required to ‘take
good faith measures to ensure that, to
the best of the contractor’s knowledge, the contractors’
subcontractors also comply
with the City’s Contractors Code of
Conduct’. The City of LA has also entered into an agreement with an NGO,
the Workers
Rights Consortium, to carry out monitoring of compliance with the
Code. This arrangement will be discussed in more detail later in
the chapter.
Thus it appears that there is a growing interest in the use of procurement
by governments in developed countries to influence labour
standards in
developing countries. However, as discussed in the following section of the
chapter, there is a lack of empirical evidence
regarding the impact of these
policies. Are these policies merely aspirational statements by governments in
developed countries under
pressure from labour and fair trade activists, or are
they designed and resourced to be legitimate and effective forms of
regulation?
Studying the Impact of Procurement as Labour Regulation
In this
section, consideration is given to whether procurement is or can be an effective
mechanism for promoting better labour standards.
In doing this, it is necessary
to outline some of the obstacles to successful use of procurement as labour
regulation. Drawing on
the regulation and governance literature and assessments
of non-government labour regulation, this chapter then outlines some possible
strategies for the effective and legitimate use of procurement to promote better
labour standards in developing countries.
Possible Barriers and
Limitations to Use of Procurement
Any study of the impact of procurement
as labour regulation must take account of any relevant barriers or limits to
this approach,
whether legal, political or economic. The first limitation is a
powerful conventional wisdom that procurement is a commercial function
of
government which must be carried out efficiently in order to ensure ‘value
for money’ for taxpayers (McCrudden 2007).
Value for money is often
assessed in narrow cost-benefit terms, that is, choosing the contractor that
will provide the best service
at the lowest cost to the public purse, thus
excluding consideration for social concerns. Even where governments adopt an
ethical
purchasing policy, purchasing officers may give such policies very
little weight compared to value for money criteria.
From the perspective of
contractors, if procurement imposes too great a cost on a business in terms of
compliance with labour standards
then legitimacy of the procurement criteria
will be undermined. Businesses may agree to labour standards, yet fail to comply
with
those standards in practice, especially if there is inadequate monitoring
and enforcement by government or its agents.
Another (related) potential
restriction arises from the promotion of competition and free trade, both at
domestic and international
regulatory levels. For example, in Australia the
Trade Practices Act 1974 (Cth) (‘TPA’) has been
identified as a potential restriction on the capacity of a State government to
use procurement to impose social
obligations on businesses supplying goods or
services to the government (Queensland Government 2006, 8.4). A number of
commentators,
however, have suggested that the TPA does not apply to
public procurement (for example Seddon 2004, Ch. 6). Nevertheless, doubts about
the extent of the TPA’s application may be a reason for State
government hesitation to strengthen labour conditions attached to public
procurement
policies.
Perhaps more significantly, both multilateral and
bilateral free trade agreements and regulatory frameworks have been identified
as
restrictions on the use of procurement to ‘discriminate’ between
businesses on the basis of labour standards, such as
the World Trade
Organisation’s Government Procurement Agreement (GPA). Once again, the
restrictions posed by such rules may
be more perceived than real. In the EU,
both the EU Treaty and the EU Public Procurement Directive 2004 are
intended to assure free movement of goods and services and non-discrimination
against
contractors on grounds of national origin. This has not prevented
national governments of member states from including labour standards
as part of
public procurement processes (Bovis 2007).
Another possible difficulty with
the use of procurement as labour regulation pertains to the potential for
regulatory complexity which
may undermine the legitimacy and effectiveness of
procurement as a mechanism for promoting better labour standards. Where used
domestically
to improve labour standards by requiring firms to adopt labour
standards and/or employment practices ‘above the floor’
of standards
set by statute, labour criteria in procurement contracts add another layer of
regulation to what is, in Australia at
least, an already complex area.
The
use of procurement as a form of transnational regulation of labour standards in
developing countries also raises a number of concerns.
Some of these barriers
are legal, in the sense that there may be constitutional or other jurisdictional
limitations on some levels
of government seeking to influence labour standards
in another country. Other challenges relate to possible unintended consequences
of a relatively developed country seeking to raise labour standards in a
developing country. Many of these have been canvassed in
relation to
non-government regulatory mechanisms – for example, that any standards set
through procurement contracts must be
sensitive to local conditions. Governments
must be sensitive to the possibility that requiring supplier businesses to
observe higher
labour standards than is their customary practice could lead to a
loss of jobs by workers in developing countries, resulting in those
workers
being ‘squeezed’ into worse jobs as a result (Heeks and Dunscombe
2003; Doorey 2005, pp 386–387).
Further concern expressed with respect
to private regulation such as supply chain regulation through codes of conduct
is that such
initiatives crowd out or undermine domestic labour law and labour
regulation institutions in developing countries (Heeks and Duncombe
2003). The
same concern could be raised in relation to attempts to use procurement as a
form of inter-state labour regulation.
Many of these challenges can be
overcome through appropriate regulatory design and implementation. The next
section provides an evaluation
of some existing procurement policies and
includes an assessment of how procurement processes could be designed to enhance
legitimacy
and effectiveness. This requires an extensive combination of public
and private regulatory approaches and mechanisms.
Procurement Strategies
for the Legitimate and Effective Promotion of Better Labour
Standards
Accepting the desirability of public procurement as a tool for
promoting better labour standards, it is important to give careful
consideration
to its design and implementation. Failure to do so may cause it to be
ineffective or have unintended consequences,
such as where the intended
beneficiaries of these initiatives end up worse off than they were beforehand
(Doorey 2005, 358). This
has been previously discussed above. Moreover, the
literature on regulation canvassed earlier serves to reinforce that unless
policy
places demands on organisations to take compliance seriously, these
approaches are likely to be nothing more than window dressing.
There are a
number of elements that must be considered in the design of a legitimate and
effective procurement process: firstly, agreement
on appropriate labour rights
and standards to be enforced through the procurement process; secondly, the
disclosure of information;
and third, an adequate system of monitoring and
enforcement of the agreed norms and standards. This last element of regulatory
design
may be reformed by the experience of non-governmental mechanisms of
international supply chain regulation and ‘ethical trade’
initiatives.
Firstly, to ensure the legitimacy of any use of procurement to
promote or secure better labour rights and standards, government must
work
responsively with their own financial officers, trade unions and their
international affiliates, the ILO, relevant NGOs and
potential contractors to
agree on appropriate labour rights and standards to be incorporated into
eligibility criteria, tender assessment
processes and the actual contracts
themselves. These standards must be adaptive to local regulation and labour
market conditions.
There have been a number of different approaches to this
challenge incorporated into voluntary codes of conduct or firm/industry-level
CSR initiatives (for example Nike and Reebok) and
‘multi-stakeholder’ non-government regulatory schemes. Many of these
initiatives are prepared in consultation with business, trade unions and NGOs,
and thus reflect the core ILO Conventions. An example
of such a scheme is the
OECD Guidelines for Multinational Enterprises (for an overview, see
Cooney 2004) Some require compliance with the labour law of the country where
work is performed, however, minimum
labour standards, especially wages, in
developing countries may not be sufficient to serve as a mechanism of poverty
alleviation.
Thus, while there is concern that labour standards in codes of
conduct are not so high as to have unintended consequences, they should
not be
so low as to be ineffective in improving working conditions.
The LA City
Sweatfree Procurement Ordinance discussed above is an example of a responsive
approach to this aspect of the procurement
challenge. Where it addresses labour
standards of sub-contractors in countries other than the US, the Ordinance
requires compliance
with local minimum standards. However, it also requires
payment of a ‘procurement living wage’ assessed on the basis
of
local conditions.
The second element of a legitimate and effective
procurement regime is a mechanism to ensure information disclosure by
contracting
companies regarding the companies and factories in their supply
chains, as well as information concerning compliance with set labour
standards
down the supply chain (Cooney 2004). If government is to ensure that only
companies with suppliers observing the minimum
standards are considered for
government contracts, there must be some mechanism by which companies must
provide this information,
and where it is subjected to some sort of monitoring
and accountability process. Such a process would prompt firms to give
consideration
to the regulatory purposes behind such a requirement, which might
encourage the internalisation of these norms. Furthermore, it allows
for
verification of compliance by independent monitors. Returning to the example of
the Sweatfree Procurement Ordinance, it appears
that contractors with the city
must provide a list of their suppliers and the location of any worksites used in
the supply of goods
and materials (WRC 2008). The city can then require that
contractors ensure that monitors can access those businesses and sites to
monitor compliance with the labour standards set under the procurement
Ordinance.
This last point brings us to monitoring and enforcement of labour
conditions in procurement contracts. Once again, the legitimacy
and
effectiveness of procurement processes to promote better labour standards would
be enhanced by the involvement of stakeholders
in the monitoring and enforcement
of standards (Vincent-Jones 2006). Evidence suggests that the procurement
process must incorporate
specifications regarding monitoring and enforcement of
compliance with the agreed labour rights and standards in order to maximise
effectiveness. Such a monitoring regime is built into the Sweatfree Communities
procurement ‘Toolkit’, (Sweatfree Communities
2006). Monitoring
might take the form of an audit of factory compliance with specified standards
as part of the tender assessment
process, or monitoring of ongoing compliance
with labour standards agreed to in procurement documentation. Ideally, these
processes
should supplement or complement private monitoring by trade unions and
NGOs, ILO and local labour regulation in order to maximise
the legitimacy of
monitoring activity (Kolben 2007). Specifications must also ensure that firms
take responsibility for implementing
internal planning and management processes
which emphasise the importance of compliance with labour criteria in procurement
contracts
(Graham and Woods 2006, 878). In other words, although governments
cannot be expected to devote significant resources to monitoring
compliance with
labour standards as part of their procurement functions, they can encourage
development of self-regulatory mechanisms
and draw on non-government monitoring
and evaluation mechanisms by requiring contractors to agree to monitoring by
trade unions,
local government agencies or independent auditing bodies.
Again, the Sweatfree Procurement Ordinance provides an excellent example of
this approach being used in relation to procurement initiatives.
By engaging the
Workers Rights Consortium (WRC) as an independent monitor of compliance with the
Ordinance, the City has adopted
an innovative model of private monitoring. The
approach of the City of LA also provides the most detailed assessment of the
impact
of procurement as mechanism for transnational labour regulation, as the
WRC has recently completed a monitoring report in relation
to compliance with
the Ordinance by a major supplier of garments to the city.
The WRC is a
non-government organisation formed in the US in 2000 as a result of protests by
students that official University apparel
in the US was being produced in
sweatshop conditions (for a detailed explanation and analysis of the WRC, see
Barenberg 2007). The
WRC both develops and monitors codes of practice designed
to ensure that participating universities and colleges source their official
garments from ‘sweatfree’ global supply chains. Mark Barenberg has
argued that ‘the WRC has developed the most
effective, transparent, and
“participatory” model of transnational labour monitoring’
(Barenberg 2007, 38). According
to Barenberg, this is largely because the WRC
maintains its independence from employer and trade union interests in the
apparel industry
in terms of its governance structure and funding sources, and
by engaging to the greatest possible extent with local workers and
communities
in carrying out factory monitoring in developing countries (Barenberg 2007).
By engaging the WRC to carry out monitoring of compliance with its
Ordinance, the City of LA has implemented this model in a procurement
context
(WRC 2008; City of Los Angeles, undated). In late 2007, the WRC carried out an
‘assessment’ of an apparel factory
in Phnomh Penh, Cambodia, owned
by a Taiwan-based multinational corporation, New Wide Garment (NWG).
Williamson-Dickie, a major supplier
of ‘Dickies’ brand garments to
the City of LA, had named NWG as one of its suppliers, and as a result NWG was
subject
to the city’s Sweatfree Ordinance. According to the WRC, NWG
employs approximately 1,400 workers at its Cambodian factory,
more than 90 per
cent of them women.
The WRC’s assessment was based on interviews with
the management and the company’s ‘code of conduct compliance
officer,
‘in-depth’ interviews with 31 NWG production employees,
review of factory documentation including payroll records, employment
contracts
and personnel policies, and a physical inspection of the factory. Unfortunately,
the WRC’s assessment report does
not provide much information on the
composition of the team used to conduct the assessment. Previous analysis of the
WRC’s
activities in relation to the monitoring of the WRC Code for
University purchasing suggests that the WRC is intended to maximise
local
participation in the assessment. In addition to including locals in the
assessment team, the WRC would normally engage with
local labour ministries,
tribunals and other officials, as well as building the capacity of local NGOs
(Barenberg 2007, 41).
WRC found that the factory was not complying with the
LA Sweatfree Ordinance in a number of respects. Some of these were instances
of
non-compliance with Cambodia’s own labour legislation, including unlawful
discrimination against pregnant workers, unlawfully
long probationary periods,
failure to provide sick leave and breach of Cambodia’s freedom of
association protections. The WRC
also found that while NWG paid workers the
minimum salary permitted by Cambodian law, this was below the Procurement Living
Wage
required by the Ordinance. The WRC estimated the Cambodian living wage at
US 63c per hour, or roughly $130 per month under the terms
of the Ordinance.
Workers were being paid between $50–62 per month.
Under the terms of
its agreement with the City of LA, the WRC held discussions with NWG and it
agreed to address some of the violations
identified in the assessment. For
example, the company agreed to adopt a policy of non-discrimination against
pregnant workers. Unresolved
issues were addressed by the WRC in the form of
recommendations to the City of LA. Interestingly, the WRC was careful not to
recommend
that the City of LA require NWG (through Williamson-Dickie) to
increase wages to meet the Procurement Living Wage. The WRC recognised
that a
wage increase could only be achieved if NWG’s customers were willing to
pay significantly higher prices for its product.
Instead, it resolved to hold
discussions with the city regarding this issue.
There are a number of
conclusions which can be drawn from this discussion regarding the ways in which
procurement mechanisms are implemented
and enforced. There are risks associated
with this mechanism for the alleviation of poverty and the promotion of higher
labour standards.
The first is that even after contractors have agreed to ensure
compliance with specified labour standards throughout their global
supply
chains, many are still likely to be non-compliant as the NWG example shows. The
second is that in the absence of monitoring,
this is likely to continue
notwithstanding that the head contractor has legal obligations to the contrary.
However, when combined
with independent and rigorous monitoring of compliance by
contractors’ supply chains, procurement can have an impact on labour
standards in developing countries. The WRC assessment report suggests that
workers at the NWG factory would enjoy improved working
conditions as a result
of the assessment, including, at the very least, a higher level of employment
security. At least some of the
employees of NWG may enjoy a less precarious
existence as a result of the LA Ordinance.
The LA Ordinance appears to
represent a rigorous and comprehensive model combining public and private
regulatory mechanisms which
could be applied more widely within the procurement
context. It involves a mechanism which is not reliant on self-regulation, but
rather relies on the Ordinance and Code to force contractor companies to engage
with the sweatfree norms not only within the contractor
company, but also across
that company’s global supply chains.
The appointment of a
well-resourced, independent monitor ensures that demands can be placed on
contractors and their suppliers to
engage with the relevant labour standards. It
also seems that the WRC is able to work closely with local groups, thus
maximising
legitimacy and effectiveness of the relevant code or policy by
ensuring that extensive evidence of compliance is collected. However,
the
approach of engaging with local workers, communities, and officials also ensures
that monitors are sensitive to local conditions
and perspectives in terms of the
course of action which is recommended.
A report by the City of LA’s
City Administrative Officer to the Chair of the Housing, Community and Economic
Development Committee
estimates that the annual cost to the City of engaging the
WRC would be in the sum of $50,000 (City of Los Angeles 2003). It is therefore
an approach which requires the expenditure of significant resources. As noted
earlier, it is questionable whether many governments
would be willing to commit
such resources to monitoring sweatfree procurement policies. In Australia, the
Sydney Olympics example
reveals that even where a policy is agreed upon,
resourcing for adequate monitoring and enforcement does not form part of the
arrangement.
That role is left to NGOs and trade unions which have many
different limitations on their resources. The alternative is to rely on
self-monitoring of supply chains by contracting companies, which on its own has
also proved to be unreliable (Barenberg 2007; Graham
and Woods 2006; Locke, Qin
and Brause 2007).
What happens when contractors and their suppliers are found
to be non-compliant with labour standards in procurement contracts? One
of the
advantages of government procurement over non-government supply chain regulation
with respect to labour standards is the extent
to which effective sanctions are
available. In most cases where government procurement contracts impose labour
standards, a basic
sanction for non-compliance will be cancellation of future
contracts and ineligibility for future government contracts (see, for
example,
the LA Sweatfree Procurement Ordinance). For many businesses, especially those
dependent on government buyers to provide
a market for their goods, exclusion
from government contracts on the basis of failure to comply with labour
standards may be a significant
penalty. This nevertheless requires a commitment
from governments to enforce sanctions where breaches are discovered in relation
to suppliers who have been long-term, preferred contractors, or where suppliers
are few and far between.
Procurement must be used to supplement existing
forms and processes of regulation and avoid overriding or conflicting with
existing
mechanisms. A combination of public and private regulation has been
shown to be effective in securing actual outcomes in terms of
better labour
standards (Weil and Mallo 2007). Thinking about effective strategies for
promotion of labour standards through procurement
also requires engagement with
the literature on private regulation and monitoring in this area. To some
degree, when considering
government purchasers as supply chain regulators, there
is a significant overlap with supply chain regulation by private purchasers
in
terms of the issues which must be confronted.
In concluding this discussion,
I am not suggesting that effective and legitimate use of procurement to promote
better labour standards
is a technocratic process of optimal regulatory design.
The barriers and challenges laid out in the previous section of this chapter
– whether real or perceived – present a significant obstacle to the
development and implementation of procurement policies
linked with labour
standards. In some contexts, especially in Australia where the use of
procurement to secure better labour standards
is relatively under-developed, an
incremental approach to the implementation of these ideas is most likely the
best that can be expected.
A relatively straightforward option for
governments to implement in the short term is to require factory list disclosure
as a condition
of eligibility and as a tender condition for procurement
contracts. That is, companies wishing to tender for government work could
be
required to disclose a list of the names and addresses of the factories which
form part of the corporation’s supply chain
(Doorey 2005; see also Kolben
2007). This proposal does not require that companies provide information
regarding the labour standards
observed by supplier factories, or that
contractors allow monitoring of compliance down their supply chains. However,
Doorey, the
proponent of this approach, argues that the factory list disclosure
proposal could address some of the barriers to enforcement of
labour standards.
It is an important first step which assists overcome the some of the expenses of
collecting compliance information.
Doorey argues that disclosure of both
supplier factories and their level of compliance can in fact lead to some
of the harmful unintended consequences for workers described earlier (Doorey
2005,
384–388). By limiting disclosure to the list of supplier factories,
there is a lower cost to both the potential contractor
and the government
because of the relative ease of providing this information and the reduction in
monitoring requirements. According
to Doorey, the information can nevertheless
empower the state and local workers and institutions in a way which does not
force workers
to be involved in something which may ultimately disadvantage
them.
Conclusion
This chapter has outlined several ways in which
government procurement can be used to achieve better labour standards and
alleviate
poverty in developing countries. Governments in developing countries
can use public wealth to leverage greater compliance with labour
standards by
contractors using suppliers in developing countries. Achieving greater
compliance with standards, including the payment
of a ‘living wage’,
will hopefully contribute to poverty reduction in those countries.
There
are, however, a number of obstacles to the effective use of public procurement
as a mechanism for the improvement of labour
standards. The first is to persuade
governments to think beyond ‘value for money’ in the context of
procurement, or at
least to see good labour practices in supply chains as an
economic benefit rather than a cost. However, even where governments have
incorporated labour standards into their procurement policies, there is very
little evidence to show that these policies are actually
effective in ensuring
compliance. Only by having adequate disclosure and monitoring arrangements will
it be possible to ensure that
procurement policies are having any effect.
It
is important to place public procurement as labour regulation in perspective.
There are natural limits to the reach of procurement
as a regulatory tool
– it only has the potential to impact on workers employed by companies
which choose to contract with government,
and their suppliers. Even where the
challenges facing this particular approach to labour regulation are overcome, it
is important
that procurement be seen as a step along the way in the achievement
of better labour standards in developing countries and not the
ultimate
goal.
References
Australian Council of Trade Unions (2006), ‘Commonwealth Games Souvenirs may Breach Labour Standards’, Media Release dated 3 March 2006, http://www.actu.asn.au/Archive/MediaandCommunication/ACTUNews/CommonwealthGamesSouvenirsMayBreachLabourStandards.aspx, last visited 9 April 2007.
Australian Labour Party (2007), National Platform: Chapter Five - Fostering Competitive and Innovative Australian Industries, available at http://www.alp.org.au/platform/chapter_05.php#5government_procurement, last accessed 17 April 2007.
Ayres, I. and Braithwaite, J. (1992), Responsive Regulation: Transcending the Deregulation Debate (New York: OUP).
Barenberg, M. (2007), ‘Toward a Democratic Model of Transnational Labour Monitoring’, in Bercusson B. and Estlund C. (eds.), Regulating Labour in the Wake of Globalization: New Challenges, New Institutions (Oxford: Hart Publishing).
Braithwaite, J. (2005), ‘Neoliberalism or Regulatory Capitalism?’ (Occasional Paper No. 5, Regulatory Institutions Network, Research School of Social Sciences, Australian National University).
Barnard, C. Deakin, S. and Hobbs, R. (2004), ‘Reflexive Law, Corporate Social Responsibility and the Evolution of Labour Standards: The Case of Working Time’, ESRC Centre for Business Research, University of Cambridge, Working Paper No. 294.
Bell, S. and Usher, A. (2007), Labour Standards in Public Procurement: Background Paper for DFID Labour Standards and Poverty Reduction Forum, 23 May 2007 (London: Ergon Associates).
Bovis, C. (2007), EU Public Procurement Law (Edward Elgar).
Black, J. (2001), ‘Decentring Regulation: Understanding the Role of Regulation and Self-Regulation in a Post-regulating World’, Current Legal Problems 54, 103.
City of Los Angeles (undated), ‘Sweat Free Ordinance Independent Monitor Agreement with Workers Rights Consortium’, http://www.sweatfree.org/policies/Sweatfree_Contractv2.10_Final.pdf, last visited 11 April 2008.
City of Los Angeles (2003), Report of the City Administrative Officer: Sweat-Free Procurement Ordinance and Amendment to Contractor Responsibility Ordinance, available at http://www.sweatfree.org/policies/lacitysweatfreereport.pdf, last accessed 11 April 2008.
Cooney, S. (2004), ‘A Broader Role for the Commonwealth in Eradicating Foreign Sweatshops’, Melbourne University Law Review 28, 290–342.
Cooney, S. (2006), ‘Exclusionary Self-Regulation: A Critical Evaluation of the AMMA's Proposal in the Mining Industry’, in Arup C. et al., Labour Law and Labour Market Regulation (Federation Press).
Department for International Development (UK) (2004), Labour Standards and Poverty Reduction (London: DFID).
Doorey, D. (2005), ‘Who Made That? Influencing Foreign Labour Practices through Reflexive Domestic Disclosure Regulation’ Osgoode Hall Law Journal 43, 353–405.
Estlund, C. (2002), ‘The Ossification of American Labor Law’, Columbia Law Review 102, 1527.
Fairtrade Foundation (2007), Buying into Fairtrade: Procurement in the Private and Public Sector (London: Fairtrade Foundation).
Graham, D. and Woods, N. (2006), ‘Making Corporate Self-Regulation Effective in Developing Countries’, World Development 34:5, 868–883.
Heeks, R. and Duncombe, R. (2003), ‘Ethical Trade: Issues in the Regulation of Global Supply Chains’, Centre on Regulation and Competition, Working Paper Series, No. 53, University of Manchester.
Howe, J. (2006), ‘“Money and Favours”: Government Deployment of Public Wealth as an Instrument of Labour Regulation’ in C Arup et al., Labour Law and Labour Market Regulation (Federation Press).
Howe, J. and Landau, I. (2007), ‘“Light Touch” Labour
Regulation by State Governments in Australia’ Melbourne University Law
Review 31.
Howe, J. (2008), ‘The Role of Light Touch Labour Regulation in Advancing Employee Participation in Corporate Governance: The Case of Partners at Work’, in Marshall, S. Mitchell, R. and Ramsay, I. (eds), [Title of Book] (Melbourne: Melbourne University Press).
International Labour Organisation (1949), The Labour Clauses (Public Contracts) Convention 1949, opened for signature 29 June 1949, ILO C94, art 2(1) (entered into force 20 September 1952) <http://www.ilo.org/ilolex/cgi-lex/convde.pl?C094> .
International Labour Office (2008), Labour Clauses in Public Contracts: Integrating the Social Dimension into Procurement Policies and Practices, General Survey Concerning the Labour Clauses (Public Contracts) Convention 1949 (No 94) and Recommendation (No 84), Report of the Committee of Experts on the Application of Conventions and Recommendations, Report III (Part 1B) for the International Labour Conference, 97th Session, 2008.
Johnstone, R. and Jones, J. (2006), ‘Constitutive Regulation of the Firm: Occupational Health and Safety, Dismissal, Discrimination and Sexual Harassment’, in Arup C. et al. (eds), Labour Law and Labour Market Regulation (Sydney: Federation Press).
Johnstone, R. and Mitchell R. (2004), ‘Regulating Work’ in Parker C. et al. (eds), Regulating Law (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Jones, M., Marshall, S. and Mitchell, R. (2007), ‘Corporate Social Responsibility and the Management of Labour in Two Australian Mining Companies’ Corporate Governance: An International Review 15:1, 56.
Kolben, K. (2007), ‘Integrative Linkage: Combining Public and Private Regulatory Approaches in the Design of Trade and Labor Regimes’, Harvard International Law Journal 48, pg.
Locke, R., Qin, F. and Brause, A. (2007), ‘Does Monitoring Improve Labour Standards? Lessons from Nike’, Industrial and Labor Relations Review 61:1, 3.
Lucio, M. and Mackenzie, R. (2004), ‘“Unstable Boundaries?” Evaluating the “New” Regulation Within Employment Relations’, Economy and Society 33, 77.
McBarnet, D. (2007), ‘Corporate Social Responsibility beyond Law, through Law, for Law: the New Corporate Accountability’, in McBarnet, D., Voiculescu, A. and Campbell, T. (eds), The New Corporate Accountability: Corporate Social Responsibility and the Law (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
McCrudden, C. (2007), Buying Social Justice (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Moon, J. (2004), ‘Government as a Driver of Corporate Social Responsibility’, No.20-2004, International Centre for Corporate Social Responsibility Research Paper Series, University of Nottingham, Nottingham.
Morgan, B. and Yeung, K. (2007), An Introduction to Law and Regulation: Text and Materials (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Office of Government Commerce (UK) (2006), Social Issues in Purchasing (London: Office of Government Commerce).
Ogus, A. (1995), ‘Rethinking Self-Regulation’ Oxford Journal of Legal Studies 15, 97.
Ogus, A. (2001), ‘New Techniques of Social Regulation: Decentralisation and Diversity’ in Collins, H. et al. (eds), Legal Regulation of the Employment Relation (London: Kluwer Law International).
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (2005), DAC Guidelines and Reference Series: Harmonising Donor Practices for Effective Aid Delivery, Volume 3: Strengthening Procurement Capacities in Developing Countries (Paris: OECD).
Parker, C. (2002), The Open Corporation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Parker, C. (2007), ‘Meta-Regulation: Legal Accountability for Corporate Social Responsibility’, in McBarnet, D., Voiculescu, A. and Campbell, T. (eds), The New Corporate Accountability: Corporate Social Responsibility and the Law (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Queensland Government, Department of Public Works (2006), State Purchasing Policy Review: Policy Paper – November 2006.
Salamon, LM. (2002), ‘The New Governance and the Tools of Public Action: An Introduction’, in Salamon, LM. (ed.), The Tools of Government: A Guide to the New Governance (place: publisher).
Scott, C. (2001), ‘Analysing Regulatory Space: Fragmentary Resources and Institutional Design’ Public Law 329.
Seddon, N. (2004), Government Contracts: Federal, State and Local (Federation Press, 3rd ed.).
SOCOG (1998), Code of Labour Practice for Production of Goods Licensed by the Sydney Organising Committee for the Olympic Games and the Sydney Paralympic Organising Committee (Sydney: SOCOG)
Sweatfree Communities (2006), Sweatfree Policy Toolkit, Sweatfree Communities and Global Exchange, available from www.sweatfree.org: accessed 12 December 2007.
Sweatfree Communities (2007), www.sweatfree.org, accessed 12 December 2007.
Teubner, G. (1983), ‘Substantive and Reflexive Elements in Modern Law’ Law and Society Review 17, 239.
Victorian Government Purchasing Board (2003), Ethical Purchasing
Policy, Victorian Government Purchasing Board
<http://www.vgpb.vic.gov.au/CA256C450016850B/0/90B9B69A95
3C1BF1CA256C7700003E65?OpenDocument>.
Webb, T. (2001), The Collaborative Games: the Story Behind the Spectacle (Sydney: Pluto Press).
Weil, D. and Mallo, C. (2007), ‘Regulating Labour Standards via Supply Chains: Combining Public/Private Interventions to Improve Workplace Compliance’, British Journal of Industrial Relations 45:4, 791–814.
Weiss, J. (2002), ‘Public Information’ in Salamon, LM. (ed.), The Tools of Government: A Guide to the New Governance (New York: Oxford University Press).
Workplace Rights Consortium (2008), WRC Assessment Re New Wide Garment (Cambodia): Findings, Recommendations and Status Report, March 6 2008 (Washington DC: WRC).
[∗] Centre for Employment and Labour Relations Law, Melbourne Law School. I would like to thank Ingrid Landau for research assistance and discussion of ideas. I am also grateful to Shelley Marshall and Kate Macdonald for helpful comments and discussions.
AustLII:
Copyright Policy
|
Disclaimers
|
Privacy Policy
|
Feedback
URL: http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/UMelbLRS/2010/16.html